By LAURA D'ANDREA TYSON and OWEN ZIDAR
economix.blogs.nytimes.com
October 19, 2012, 6:00 am
The centerpiece of
Mitt Romney's tax plan is an across-the-board 20 percent cut in marginal tax
rates. This cut, along with a few other tax changes Mr. Romney has endorsed -
such as repeal of the estate tax and the alternative minimum tax - would reduce
federal tax revenue from personal income and payroll taxes by an estimated $3.6 trillion to $3.8 trillion over 10 years.
The total is closer
to $5 trillion when Mr. Romney's proposed cut in the corporate
income tax rate to 25 percent is included. About two-thirds of this amount would go to taxpayers making
$200,000 a year or more - about 5 percent of all taxpayers.
Extending the Bush
tax cuts for high-income earners, as Mr. Romney proposes, adds another trillion in lost revenue and increases the share of
the benefits going to the top 5 percent. Even if the cost of the Romney tax
cuts for the top 5 percent is covered by base-broadening measures, as Mr. Romney
promises - but as President Obama and many others assert is mathematically impossible - does it make sense to
devote trillions of dollars to lowering income taxes for the top 5 percent? Is
this an effective way to create jobs?
Mr. Romney appears to think so. His plan rests on the assertion that
lower taxes for high-income taxpayers will increase economic activity and
employment - that lower taxes for job creators create jobs and will do so
quickly. This assertion, while superficially convincing and ideologically
compelling, is not supported by the evidence.
If tax cuts for high-income earners generate substantial real economic activity
and job creation, then we should expect to see two things in the data. First,
employment growth should be stronger in the years after tax cuts for these
earners. Second, parts of the country with a larger share of high-income
earners should experience stronger employment growth after national tax cuts
for these taxpayers, because the places where they live receive a larger share
of the national tax cuts.
What do we actually
see after combing through a half-century of economic data? Neither of these predictions
is borne out.
The graph below,
based on our research, shows the relationship between the cumulative
change in income and payroll tax liabilities for the top 5 percent over a
two-year period as a share of gross domestic product and employment growth in
the two years after the change.
The graph and the
regression analysis on which it is based reveal that there is no link between
income tax cuts for the top 5 percent and subsequent job creation. (We also
examined the relationship between tax cuts for the top 10 percent and
subsequent job creation and found the same result.)
The table below
highlights three of these tax changes -- the Reagan tax cut of 1982, the
Clinton tax increase of 1993 and the Bush tax cut of 2003 - and subsequent
employment growth. Strong employment growth followed the Reagan cut, but the
employment growth following the Clinton
tax increase exceeded the employment growth following the Bush tax cut, which
was comparable in size to the Reagan cut.
Job growth at the
state level after national tax cuts for high-income earners confirms the
absence of a strong link between such cuts and the pace of job creation in the
next two years.
The next graph shows
no substantial link between tax cuts for the top 10 percent and the pace of job
creation at the state level. Employment growth in states with a large share of
rich people, such as Connecticut or New Jersey, was not much faster, on
average, than it would have been otherwise after the Reagan and Bush tax cuts
for the top 10 percent and wasn't much slower, on average, after the Clinton
tax increase on this group.
If there really were
a strong link between job creation and tax cuts for high-income "job
creators," we should be able to see the effects somewhere. But we have
found no evidence that such cuts lead to substantially faster employment growth
at the national, state or even ZIP-code level.
Tax cuts for
everyone else are a much more effective path to job creation. Our research found
a statistically significant and positive relationship between tax cuts for the
bottom 95 percent and job growth at both the national and state levels. The
graph below shows the relationship for the national data. Our results indicate
that almost all of the stimulative effect of income and payroll tax cuts on job
creation in the short to medium run result from such cuts for the bottom 95
percent.
Lower-income
taxpayers spend a higher share of their tax cuts. Many of these taxpayers often
have more difficulty borrowing money and tapping into their housing wealth than
higher-income individuals. These demand-side
forces explain why consumption goes up much more after tax cuts for
the bottom 95 percent than after equivalently sized cuts for the top 5 percent.
An increase in consumption, which still accounts for about 70 percent of
G.D.P., fuels increases in demand, and that leads companies to create more
jobs. In survey after survey, businesses confirm that changes in demand are the
primary determinant of their employment decisions.
Investment also
increases after tax cuts for the bottom 95 percent, suggesting that shifting
moderately size tax cuts to the bottom 95 percent from the top 5 percent isn't
a zero-sum trade-off between consumption and investment.
Instead, an increase
in demand and economic activity because of an increase in consumption also
makes investment more attractive, especially in difficult economic conditions.
Over all, our research shows that tax cuts for the bottom 95 percent are
much more effective than tax cuts for the top 5 percent at increasing job
creation in the subsequent two years.
Other analysts reach
similar conclusions. For example, the Congressional Budget Office and Mark Zandi, Moody's chief economist, find that tax cuts for
lower-income recipients generate larger increases in employment per dollar cost
to the federal budget than comparable tax cuts for high-income taxpayers in the
short run.
What about the long
run? A recent report by the Congressional Research Service found no
clear relationship between cuts in marginal tax rates that primarily benefit
high-income taxpayers and economic growth and job creation. A recent review by three distinguished academic economists also
found no convincing evidence that real economic activity responds materially to
tax-rate changes on top income earners, although such rate changes do affect
their tax-avoidance behavior.
Cross-country comparisons also do not show a close link between top marginal
rates and growth. While these studies don't find large effects in the long run,
we note that these long-run effects are harder to measure and are thus more
uncertain.
Nevertheless, if the
priority is to create a substantial number of jobs over the next presidential
term, evidence from the last half-century strongly suggests that tax cuts for
the top 5 percent won't work. Tax cuts for working families, tax cuts directly
aimed at expanded hiring or increases in infrastructure investment would have
much more bang for the buck and would cost much less in terms of forgone
revenue and deficit reduction in the future.
With elevated
unemployment, weakness in Europe and slowing
growth in emerging economies, fiscal measures that actually increase economic
activity and employment in the near term are required. Our research shows that
tax cuts for the rich do not meet this standard.